The main assumptions and theses of the monetarist school in economics

Authors

  • Zbigniew Klimiuk Mazowiecka Uczelnia Publiczna w Płocku

DOI:

https://doi.org/10.19251/rtnp/2021.13(6)

Keywords:

macroeconomic doctrine, monetarism, Keynesianism and neo-Keynesianism, quantity theory of money, money supply and demand, inflation, monetary approach to the balance of payments, the monetarist interpretation of unemployment, stagflation, transmission mechanism

Abstract

The term monetarism as a term for the macroeconomic doctrine associated and identified explicitly with Milton Friedman and the University of Chicago was coined by Karl Brunner in 1968. It gained importance on theoretical grounds in the late 1960s and early 1970s, and achieved its greatest impact on economic policy in the late 1970s and early 1980s. It owed its popularity to the prevailing stagflation of the 1970s. Just as the Great Depression had shaken faith in the market and liberalism, stagflation caused a retreat from Keynesian economics and a rebirth of classical ideas. On theoretical grounds, a new and more radical school - the new classical economics - grew out of monetarism. However, it was monetarism that became part of the mainstream and the reference point for most of the discussions revolving around key theoretical issues and the role of the state in the economy. M. Friedman, born in 1912 in New York, one of the most prominent and controversial economists of the 20th century was the founder of monetarism. From the very beginning of his academic career, he was an ardent supporter of economic liberalism, and from these positions he consistently and on every occasion criticized Keynesianism, as well as neo-Keynesianism. In his opinion, market imperfections resulted from state interference in the country’s economy, and also from the monopolistic position of trade unions. He also believed that all expenditures for the improvement of the economy, as well as social protection of the poorest social groups, were unjustified. The state should limit its activities to the maintenance of public order and safety and uphold the law, especially the right to private property. Looking at the growth of the monetarist school through the lens of its historical development, we clearly see three stages. It began with the evolution of the quantity theory of money approach from the mid-1950s to the mid-1960s, through the expectations-supported Phillips curve analysis that monetarist analysis assimilated in the second half of the 1960s, and ended with the monetary approach to balance of payments and exchange rate determination that was incorporated into monetarist analysis in the early 1970s. Researchers associated with the monetarist school emphasize the pro-cyclical role of the money supply (i.e. the ahead of time movement of other variables such as wages, prices, production - both in nominal and real terms).
Therefore, the central bank should ensure a constant rate of increase in the money supply (the so-called k-percentage rule) setting it at the level of 3-5% per year for the economy. The proposal of such a growth rate of supply resulted from the fact that this was the natural growth rate of the supply potential of the economy. According to monetarists, in the long run the economy approaches the state of full exploitation of production potential, so if the amount of money in circulation grows at the same rate as production, the average price level does not change, so there is no inflation.

References

Adelman I., Theories of Economic Growth and Development, Stanford, Calif., Stanford University Press 1961.

Ball L. and Romer D., Real Rigidities and the Non-neutrality of Money, Review of Economic Studies, 1990, Volume 57, s. 183-203.

Bartkowiak R., Historia myśli ekonomicznej, PWE, Warszawa 2003.

Begg D., Makroekonomia, PWE, Warszawa 2007.

Bludnik I., Neokeyensizm, w: Współczesne teorie ekonomiczne, red. M. Ratajczak, Uniwersytet Ekonomiczny w Poznaniu, Poznań 2012.

Boskin M. J., Tax Policy and Economic Growth: Lessons From the 1980s, “Journal of Economic Perspectives”, Vol. 2, No. 4/1988.

Bludnik I., Neokeynesizm. Analiza krytyczna, Wydawnictwo Uniwersytetu Ekonomicznego w Poznaniu, Poznań 2011.

Burda M., Wyplosz C., Makroekonomia, Warszawa 2000.

Chrabonczewska E., Teoria i polityka kursu walutowego, Warszawa 1996.

Davidson P., A technical definition of uncertainty and the long-run nonneutrality of money, “Cambridge Journal of Economics”, 1988, Vol. 12, No. 3, s. 329–337.

Drabowski E., Wpływ pieniądza na gospodarkę w teoriach keynesizmu i monetaryzmu, PWN, Warszawa 1987.

Feldstein M. (ed.), American Economic Policy in the 1980s, University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1994.

Frenkel J. A. and Johnson H. G. (eds), The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments, London: Allen & Unwin 1976.

Friedman M., Essays in positive economics, Chicago: University of Chicago Press 1959.

Friedman M., Lessons from the 1979-82 monetary policy experiment, „American Economic Review” 74, Nr 2/1984, s. 397-400.

Friedman M., The methodology of positive economics, in: Essays In Positive Economics, University of Chicago Press, Chicago 1966, s. 3–43.

Friedman M., Wolny wybór, Sosnowiec 1994.

Gordon R., Understanding Inflation in the 1980s‖, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 16 (1)/1985.

Hall R., Makroekonomia, PWN, Warszawa 2000.

Hayek von F., Indywidualizm a porządek ekonomiczny, Kraków 1998.

Johnson, H. G., The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments: a Nontechnical Guide, “Journal of International Economics”, Vol. 7/1977, s. 251–68.

Kacperski J., Szkoła austriacka wobec socjalizmu i współczesnych problemów wolnego rynku, Warszawa 2009.

Kalicki K., Pieniądz a bilans płatniczy, Warszawa 1998.

Kamerschen D.R., Ekonomia, Fundacja Gospodarcza NSZZ „Solidarność”, Gdańsk 1993.

Kwiatkowski E., Bezrobocie. Podstawy teoretyczne, Warszawa 2001.

Landreth H. , D. Colander, Historia myśli ekonomicznej, Warszawa 2005.

Landreth H., D.C. Colander, Historia myśli ekonomicznej, Warszawa 1998.

Łaski K., Strukturalne przyczyny kryzysu finansów publicznych w Unii Europejskiej, PAN, „Economic Studies” 2011, nr 1.

Lis S., Współczesna makroekonomia, Wydawnictwo Uniwersytetu Ekonomicznego w Krakowie, Kraków 2011.

Lucas R., On the mechanics of economic development, „Journal of Monetary Economics”, Vol. 22 No. 1/1988, s. 3-42.

Maddison, A., Phases of capitalist development, Oxford University Press, Oxford 1982.

Mankiw N.G., Makroekonomia, PWE, Warszawa 2009.

McDermott J., Mercantilism and Modern Growth, „Journal of Economic Growth”, Vol. 4, Issue 1/1999, pp.55-80.

Milewski R., Elementarne zagadnienia ekonomii, Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN, Warszawa 1998.

Nasiłowski M., Historia myśli ekonomicznej, Warszawa 1998.

Popławska E., Ekonomia – Makroekonomia, Warszawa 1997.

Próchnicki L., Makroekonomia. Zrozumieć Gospodarkę, Zachodniopomorska Szkoła Biznesu, Szczecin 2000.

Próchnicki L., Nowa szkoła keynesowska – teoretyczne i polityczne implikacje, „Studia i Prace Wydziału Nauk Ekonomicznych i Zarządzania”, Nr 19/2011.

Ratajczak M., Współczesne teorie ekonomiczne, Wydawnictwo Akademii Ekonomicznej w Poznaniu, Poznań 2012.

Reid, G., Classical Economic Growth: An Analysis in the Tradition of Adam Smith, Basic Blackwell Ltd, New York 1989.

Romer P., Human Capital And Growth: Theory and Evidence, NBER Working Papers 3173, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc 1989.

Romer P., Endogenous technological change, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA 1989.

Rosati D., R. Michalski, Inflacja, Warszawa 1989.

Rostow W. and Kennedy M., Theorists of economic growth from David Hume to the present, Oxford University Press, New York 1990.

Samuelson P., Ekonomia, Warszawa 1995.

Sargent T.J., Rational Expectations, the Real Rate of Interest and the Natural Rate of Unemployment, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1973, Vol. 2.

Skawińska E., K. Sobiech, K. Nawrot, Makroekonomia – teoretyczne i praktyczne aspekty gospodarki rynkowej, Warszawa 2008.

Snowdon B., H. Vane, P. Wynarczyk, Współczesne nurty teorii makroekonomii, Warszawa 1998.

Snowdon B., Vane H., Dynarczyk P., Współczesne nurty teorii makroekonomii, Warszawa 1998.

Solow R., A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth, „The Quarterly Journal of Economics”, Vol. 70 No. 1/1956, s. 65-94.

Solow R., Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function, „The Review of Economics and Statistics”, Vol. 39 No. 3/1957, s. 312-320.

Soto de Huerta J., Szkoła austriacka, Warszawa 2010.

Stankiewicz W., Historia myśli ekonomicznej, Warszawa 2007.

Taylor J.B., Aggregate dynamics and staggered contracts, „Journal of Political Economy”, Vol. 88, No. 1/1980, s. 1–23.

Taylor J.B., Changes in American Economic Policy in the 1980s: Watershed or Pendulum Swing?, “Journal of Economic Literature”, Vol. 33, No. 2, June/1995, s. 777-784.

Temkin G., Dyskusje o gospodarce socjalistycznej: Marks- Lange- Mises- Hayek, Warszawa 2008.

Throop A. W., Fiscal Policy in the Reagan Years: A Burden on Future Generations?, “Economic Review”, No. 1/1991.

Wiktorowski K., Historia myśli ekonomicznej, Polskie Towarzystwo Ekonomiczne, Szczecin 2003.

Wojtyna A., Ewolucja keynesizmu a główny nurt ekonomii, PWE, Warszawa 2000.

Woodford M., Convergence in macroeconomics: Elements of the new synthesis, „American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics”, Vol. 1, No. 1/2009, s. 267–279.

Published

2022-03-10